This was originally part of the main ICC blog post, but I split it off because it got too long.
Read this first: ICC
funding comes after publication
For many products, there is a large up-front cost required to even begin work on completing it. This is true for almost all physical products, especially tech hardware. ICC has no solution for these cases. It instead focuses on information-based products, like art and music and software, as they can usually be broken down into sub-tasks, their distribution costs are almost zero, and the cost to the author to get started is generally very low.
The risk has to go somewhere, whether it is the funder risking the loss of their investment or the producer risking the loss of the work they put in. The reason ICC decides the money has to come after is because fluidity is important to the scoring process, and money is more fluid than the deliverable (i.e. you can't release 90% of an artwork, but you can provide 90% of the funding). Also, since there are generally far more funders than producers in any given transaction, it makes more sense to treat the funders as a more consistent collective decision-making body than the producers.
This is all to say that ICC isn't a viable means of funding for someone with very little starting funds, so this will likely be used as either as a side gig to complement a separate, more stable income, or for artists who already have a significant fanbase. However, no other method of funding really allows artists to start from zero financial or social resources without putting all the risk on the funder.
ziglang bounty post
(added 23-268)
https://ziglang.org/news/bounties-damage-open-source-projects/
This blog post highlights many issues with bounties that might also apply to ICC:
Bounties foster competition at the expense of cooperation.
Possibly also applies to ICC. It depends on how an organization decides to distribute a pledge that multiple people worked on, and ICC makes few moves, if any, to help with this. The case that I see being the most common is that donation payouts are shared, and new contributors get a reduced share (the rest goes to maintainer) until they reach some threshold. This has many downsides:
- for maximum payout, a contributor is encouraged work on a task alone
- new contributors are considered outsiders with reduced entitlements
- without good management, there might be conflicts when multiple members work on the same task
In the case of an organization with multiple members, perhaps it makes more sense for all donations to a project to go to one big pool, and for there to be some other decision-making process for deciding how the donations are distributed.
battle royale dynamics
Instead of scouting for a suitable candidate, you’re letting battle royale dynamics pick a winner for you, at the expense of everybody who’s going to lose the competition.
This observation highlights the importance of tying the pledge not just to a work, but also to the creator. If a different creator produces interchangably similar work, it is hopefully obvious that they should not be entitled to all of the pledges that were made towards this creator's work.
Likewise, by reducing or eliminating the payout in the case that an outsider completes a task, these battle royale dynamics do not form, and a suitable candidate can still be carefully selected.
risk allocation
Instead of creating a clear contract where you take on some of the risk, you implicitly put the entirety of the risk on the contestants (eg partial solutions don’t get any payout).
A later point that I believe is also related:
Instead of spreading unease to all the people involved, it would be preferable you instead learned how to do business properly.
The allocation of risk to contestants only forms when the criteria for payout is simply completing the task. As long as the payout is tied to both the work and the creator, ICC does not allocate risk any more poorly than it would be in a donation-based scheme. That is, because payouts don't go to drive-by contributors, the risk of two people working on the same task is the same as it is in any other FOSS project since there is no financial incentive for people not associated with the organization (assuming the organization does a good job allocating work, which, to be fair, is not a given).
reckless action to pass a test suite
Instead of allocating time and resources to proper due diligence, you instead penalize any form of thoughtfulness in favor of reckless action (eg a solution just needs to pass a test suite).
As far as I can tell, this is less relevant due to converse crowdfunding. Thoughtfulness is still required because the final arbiter for quality is the donor, who can use whatever subjective mechanisms are necessary to assess quality.
software lifecycle considerations
Instead of planning for the full lifecycle of software, which also includes maintenance, you end up with a quickly bitrotting artifact that is of no practical use to anybody.
Funding maintenance is definitely a concern, especially for larger projects. ICC does not work well in cases where a few very wealthy organizations all want the same thing, and most open source libraries fall under this case. Maintenance is incredibly important (I think most developers would say that it's even more important than new features), but very boring (both for maintainer and user) and hard to fund.
The Zig post goes one step further and highlights that if a contributor cares more about the payout than the long-term sustainability of the project, then their priorities discourage them from submitting maintainable code.
For individual artists, this seems like an easy, though not trivial, obstacle to overcome. My worries are greater when it comes to larger organizations and more complex projects (like Zig). I've been simmering on an organizational structure that can work in tandem with ICC, but I'm skeptical as to whether it will actually work:
All donations go to the organization, and is distributed based on "shares", which are received when one completes a task. As a result, the contributor gets much less up front, but over time, they get a portion of all future donations. This encourages contributors to make their contributions more sustainable over the long term.
While this seems better than simply giving all the donations to the contributor that completes the task, I am a little hesitant to prescribe such a bureaucracy, and I think this is something that should be figured out by the organization in question.
social pressure
On projects less radical than Zig, you might also put pressure on the development team to accept the winning submission, which, given the above, will probably not be the most well-thought-out and maintainable solution.
I have no solution, except crossing my fingers and hoping people are reasonable and understanding about this.
conclusion
As I understand it, the conflict in the WASIX issue linked in the Zig blog post mainly stemmed from the fact that implementing WASIX would not have aligned with the goals of Zig. Even though the bounty payout is not contingent on the implementation being accepted into the mainline branch, it is understandable how this bounty could be used as a tool to subvert the goals of the leadership and community to push the progress of the project in a direction that its participants don't want it to go in (another relevant section). While this concern is not explicitly mentioned in the Zig blog post, it highlights yet another important aspect of ICC: the artist is the sole entity that is allowed to create new proposals. Before, I had made this decision because I thought it would be annoying and unwieldy for the donors to be able to create new proposals (not to mention the logistical headache of determining when two proposals are similar enough to combine into one). However, as this conflict shows, it is absolutely imperative for proposal creation and modification to be restricted to the artist in order to preserve artistic freedom, and it is perhaps worth looking into additional protections.
Most of these points seem extremely pertinent to ICC (especially the last two), and are worth thorough analysis during and after the initial test run. It should not be understated the degree to which these issues could result in harming FOSS more than it helps. The worst outcome for this is that it leads to the destruction of a FOSS project that would have otherwise survived, without preserving a project that would have otherwise died.
does not solve the FOSS maintenance crisis
The Tidelift open source maintainer survey report contains a lot of disheartening results:
- 60% of maintainers are unpaid
- Maintainers are spending 3x more time on security than they did a few years ago
- In the wake of the xz utils hack, two-thirds of maintainers are less trusting of contributors
- The open source maintainer community is getting grayer (i.e. older)
Unlike a developer, a maintainer's role is less to implement new desired features, and more to ensure that a software project continues to work in the future as the world around it changes. This entails bug fixes, security improvements, using updated dependencies, and adding support for newer hardware, to name a few. Most of these things aren't really things people would be willing to pay for in an ICC scheme, at least not in the numbers required to justify the work.
Bullshit Jobs is my least favorite David Graeber book, but one of the takeaways I got from reading it is that one of the reasons many important jobs (nursing, teaching, waste management, etc) pay poorly is because extortion is an important part of wage negotiations (if you don't pay me more, I will leave this job), and people are less willing to withold their labor when they think what they're doing is an important, or even critical thing that needs to be done.
In a way, every quid pro quo financial transaction is extortion (for example, buying food at a grocery store), and since ICC may imply this sort of transaction, a maintainer may feel uncomfortable signaling that the only thing standing between them and fixing this important piece of infrastructure is getting paid. I would argue that the implied contract of "if you produce it, I will fund this" is not a contract in the case of ICC since the donor is allowed to refuse with no repercussion other than the system knowing that they pledged some amount and didn't contribute it.
artistic freedom
I personally believe that this method allows for more artistic freedom than copyright-based compensation schemes (like commissions). I have no real basis for believing this, and will be on the lookout for the effects of this funding method on artistic freedom when I see more data.
In the end, the producer still gets final say in what they choose to do. Even if one option has significantly more fund offers than the others, the artist is still justified in deciding to do one of the others, and those who offered to pay for the most popular one don't lose any money from this.
more money means more influence
In general, people with more money have more power, and if implemented without careful intent, this tool will likely cause the same power consolidation effects of many other market systems. One way to counteract this is some sort of voting system where each person gets a single vote, but that has its own complications in verifying that all of the voters are actually distinct people (and not bots or malicious actors), or the fact that some people are more reliant on a project than others. That being said, the goal with ICC is to make money flow to people making cool things, with no regard for power, and the currently targeted demographic is one that is very conscious of how money and power flow. I've seen very few people who pursue art or FOSS software out of a desire for money and power. This is also why my platform (as is currently planned) requires FOSS and/or Creative Commons licensing, as it filters out the people for whom this is exclusively a means of making more money (which isnt to say that making money can't be someone's primary goal).
Another potential concern is that an individual with a large amount of money could basically have monopoly-level artistic influence over a large part of digital art production. However, if this platform led to a small amount of people paying artists large amounts of money to produce what they (both the funder and the producer) want, I'd say thats an outcome I'd be willing to work with.
That being said, the hope is that most of the income comes from a large number of individuals instead of a couple rich people or big companies. If you're paying for something, it's because you're getting something out of it in return, and ideally, a large number of people should be getting something from these projects. Plus, if you're not paying, you have no say in what gets made.
low variance and regular output producers
For a producer who only produces one type of content at a fixed interval, there isn't much economic benefit to incremental converse crowdfunding over methods like crowdfunded patronage or donation.
case study: 99% Invisible
The main work that 99% Invisible produces is their weekly podcast discussing design. There isn't really any reason for a listener to pledge towards a "Release a podcast" product offering, as the quality, quantity, and timing of that deliverable would be practically the same regardless of funding amount. Moreover, part of the joy of the podcast is revealing a part of the built world that is often underappreciated, so holding a poll to decide on the topic of the next podcast would be antithetical to this premise. For this type of creator, it would make more sense to run funding drives (which, last time I checked, is what 99% Invisible does), use a platform like Ko-fi or Patreon, or seek public funding.
research
(added 23-104)
It goes without saying that research is an important part of the development process. I believe ICC would not be ideal for directly funding research for a few reasons:
- The value of research is hard to know before it is done. Using exploration of a forest as an analogy, the biggest and most important breakthroughs aren't those that cover the largest area, but rather those in the path that connect the starting point to the destination.
- It is hard to break down into smaller increments, as the value is really only realized in aggregate. A deliverable like "produce a reliable method to sense the position of a shuttle along a rail" would have so many factors involved in its assessment that even with conditional offerings, it would be difficult to express the suitability across the various use cases, and how the final solution navigates the many tradeoffs involved.
accessibility
(added 23-268)
Accessibility improvements only really get done via central planning measures (at a small scale, Apple, at larger scales, the American Disability Act). I don't forsee ICC hurting current accessibility efforts, but it is important to recognize that this is not really a "rising tide that lifts all boats" in FOSS and free culture, and that other measures are necessary.
See also: https://hachyderm.io/@ekuber/112718152844250234
#OpenSource and #FreeSoftware is predicated on people "scratching their own itch", with the expectation that if a solution is useful to you, it will likely be useful to others. But that breaks down when it comes to hard, niche problems that require specialized knowledge and skills. Things like good #accessibility in desktop environments doesn't happen without lots of effort, knowledge and intent.
getting scooped
If you're a video essayist, you might want to create proposals that describe the topic of the proposed video in detail. However, doing so could result in a lower-effort essayist "scooping" your topic before you. While it would be interesting to see how the essayist would combat that (perhaps by using the "scoop" as another reference to fact check their own video, or to gauge the audience reaction and use that to expand on some parts and remove others), in general, the best move is probably to use more vague descriptions of the topics in their proposals.
a bit complicated
One of the claimed benefits of Ko-fi over other platforms is its simplicity. ICC at its base level is a non-negligible amount of stuff to be aware of, and once you incorporate details like sub-deliverables and expected donation score and conditional offerings, it becomes an economic labyrinth. In addition, the onus is on the donor to determine to what extent the creator has satisfied their claims, which is additional work that not a lot of supporters are willing to put the time and energy into.
Notably, the game engine Bevy observed that when it moved from a simple system (send all money to the creator/maintainer) to a more complex system (choose which contributer to send money to), new donors went way down.
money corrupts the joy of creation
In some cases where there is no financial incentive, there's a lot more passion, in part out of necessity. But such a scenario is almost never financially sustainable.
money is not an ideal driver for an organization
Big multi-person projects will fall apart if the main thing holding them together is money. These things need vision and a group of people who collectively hold it, especially early on. For money to be the sole motivator is inviting failure, and in the case that it makes it past the early stages, leads to an organization that is driven by a perverse incentive.
CC-BY-NC
Not really an issue with the actual mechanism behind ICC, but it's probably not legal for an artist to use this as a platform for a work that triggers the non-commercial restrictions of a Creative Commons license. While ICC is a framework for donation (it does not transfer any rights or meaningful property in exchange for the donation), I belive the non-commercial restriction still triggers even in the case of donation-funded media (like Blender open movies). Just something that it's probably worth clarifying to the artist.
this seems pretty consumerist
Sure, this does "encourage the acquisition of goods and services in ever-increasing amounts" (which is how Wikipedia defines consumerism), but in moderation, isn't that a good thing?
Though if you're looking for a less commerce-driven solution, here are some options:
- lobby politicians to increase funding for public services like radio and television
- publicly voice support for your country's endowments and fellowships (like the National Endowment for the Arts)
- support the artists in your local and online communities
- go commission a profile picture or something. artists are really good
at that kind of thing, and its really satisfying to show off something
that was made just for you. also maybe like a ringtone.
https://banchan.art/RIP- (arguably also commerce-driven)
- https://comradery.co/: Democratic cooperative Patreon alternative
- https://resonate.coop/pricing/: Alternative funding model for music streaming
- Benn Jordan's proposal of socialized copyright
donor entitlement
In order to preserve artistic autonomy, it must be abundantly clear that even if a proposal has the highest expected payout, it is not guaranteed to be the top priority. The creator should always be the one making the final decision, and they should ideally be completely unencumbered in their decision. Of course, reality is a poor fit for ideals, and even if someone was totally free to do whatever they wanted in their project, we live in a society with laws and costs of living that will influence what they are willing or capable of doing.
closing statement
For the foreseeable future, any attempt to fund a cool public project is a balance of doing the right thing for the future of the project and finding a sustainable source of income. If improvements came without costs and sacrifices, then things would be much easier. Hopefully, this paradigm is an improvement on the options currently available, but that remains to be seen.